Sunday, December 18, 2011

Fundamentals of Value Creation - Part II

This is part II of my previous post on the Fundamentals of Value Creation. In part I, we described how value creation can be quantitatively captured by looking at two key variables: growth rate (g) of NOPAT and return on invested capital (ROIC). If you are not familiar with these concepts, I recommend you read part I (here) before continuing. 

A computer could easily give you a list of all companies that have grown at healthy rates and at ROIC that consistently exceeded the cost of capital by some reasonably wide margin. In fact, Joel's Greenblatt's "Magic Formula" screen (based on his book Little Book that Beats the Market) is programmed to almost do this - find high ROIC companies trading at cheap valuations. The formula has shown to work well if you stay disciplined and stick to the formula even when it looks like it isn't working. 

I believe a "defensive" investor (investors that are unable to devote much time to the process of investing) will be well served by just sticking to the prescriptions laid out by Mr. Greenblatt in his book. However, for the "enterprising" investor (investors that are willing to put the time and thought required for the process of making sound investing decisions) the edge is in going one step further and digging answers to questions like:
  1. Why does an industry on average generate a high (or low) ROIC? (I'll just focus on ROIC instead of g since analyzing the drivers of g are well popularized).
  2. Why is this company's ROIC so much higher (or lower) than the industry?
  3. Can it continue to perform at these levels? What will be the impact of management's current actions on  company's future ROIC? 
Fortunately, I am not the first one to ask these questions. Renowned Harvard Business School professor, Michael Porter, addressed these questions in his two books that are now classics, Competitive Strategy (1980) and Competitive Advantage (1985) and numerous other HBR articles published since then.

Returns in a business are highly dependent on the industry in which it operates. Pharmaceutical and biotechnology companies protected by patents have produced a median returns of 23.5%, whereas most airlines have destroyed capital.


The reason for difference in industries performance lies mainly in differences between their competitive structures. When most people think of competition, they think of the rivals trying to earn the sale. However, competition for returns is actually a struggle between multiple players, not just rivals, over who will capture the value an industry creates. It's true, of course, that companies compete for profits with their rivals. But they are also engaged in a struggle for profits with their customers, who would be happy to pay less and get more. They compete with their suppliers, who would always be happier to be paid more and deliver less. They compete with producers who make products that could be substituted for their own. And they compete with potential rivals as well as existing ones, because even the threat of new entrants place limits on how much they can charge their customers. These five forces - the intensity of rivalry among existing competitors, the bargaining power of buyers, the bargaining power of suppliers, the threat of substitutes, and the threat of new entrants - determine the industry's competitive structure which in turn determine to a large degree the returns that a business in that industry generates.

The best way to learn about the five forces framework is to apply it to a specific industry. We'll use the example of the airline industry to gain a much deeper insight into the underlying reasons for the industry's poor record for value creation.

Intensity of Rivalry:
Rivalry in the airline industry is highly intense. Intensive rivalry is a driven by a number of underlying characteristics of airline transport. At its core, the aggressive buildup of capacity that never leaves the industry drives pricing decisions that fail to support attractive returns.
  1. Perishable Product: An unfilled airline seat cannot be stored. Costs for providing capacity are thus largely sunk in the short term thus creating severe pressure on price discounting. 
  2. Undifferentiated Product: The product offered is highly similar across airlines as new product features (flat bed, entertainment system etc.) are quickly imitated among peers. 
  3. Low Marginal Cost Structure: High fixed costs exist at the level of individual aircraft, marginal costs for adding additional customers are very low, which further reinforces price discounting.
  4. High Exit Barriers: The disappearance of capacity and exit of companies are two key adjustment mechanisms through which other industries support normal returns. In the airline industry, neither of the two adjustment mechanisms work: 
    • Aircraft capacity can easily be deployed to different geographic markets. Thus, even if particular companies might leave the market, airline capacity usually stays in the market, and disappears only in the long run. 
    • Less than 1% of airlines exit the market in an average year. 
      • Governments have a tradition of bailing out airlines. In the US, Chapter 11 forces the debtors to provide the bailout; both mechanisms allow companies to shed some of their fixed costs. Management is often not held accountable in a bailout, reducing the disincentives for managers to avoid going through such periods. 
      • There are also specific other barriers that limit airlines ability to reduce capacity overall and on specific routes. 
        • Airlines are forced to take a capital loss charge if they sell an aircraft in a downturn. Getting out of a leasing contract is equally costly in a downturn. Keeping capacity idle is costly, but it avoids the capital loss. 
        • Gradual reduction in capacity is also complicated by need to retire by aircraft, not by seat. 
        • Use-it-or-lose-it rules on airport slots create barriers to exit from routes. Losing a connection can have ripple effects on other parts of the network for carriers that use the hub-and-spoke-model. 
        • And lastly, reducing capacity by moving to a smaller aircraft on specific connections increases the average cost per available seat kilometer. 
Bargaining Power of Customers:
Customer bargaining power is high and rising driven by the following factors:
  1. Power of Channels:
    • Aggregator website have concentrated consumers' buying power. Their focus on price comparison has significantly increased the transparency of prices across carriers. Global distributions systems (GDSs) have made it very easy for new aggregator websites to enter the market. The strong market power of the three dominant GDSs has triggered the current conflict between GDSs and US airlines.
    • Travel agents now often represent the entire demand of large corporate clients, with significant power to move demand across carriers. Furthermore, agents have to comply with corporate policies that have become more price oriented.
  2. Power of End Consumers:
    • Air travel for leisure customers is a significant discretionary spending item, increasing price sensitivity.
    • Switching costs are very low for leisure customers. Loyalty programs primarily matter to those who are traveling extensively on business.
    • Frequency of a particular route is the key (and probably the only) differentiator among airlines of a similar type for a given connection for business travelers.
Bargaining Power of Suppliers
The bargaining power of suppliers is high for several critical inputs.
  1. Airframe and engine manufacturers:
    • Airframe and engine manufacturers are highly concentrated globally. These suppliers have high bargaining power.
    • Switching costs between airframes and engines are modest. There are some fixed costs of introducing a new type of aircraft/engine to a fleet. For new aircraft, the often significant type lag between order and production create some switching barriers.
    • Airframe and engine manufacturers have important alternate markets that they can sell to, especially the market for defense equipment.
    • Airframe manufacturers have thus far not exploited their bargaining power to maximize their short-term returns. They have, however, been able to shift most of the market risk associated with aircraft purchases to airlines.
    • The aggressive competition between aircraft manufacturers has hurt the airline industry structure by encouraging aggressive capacity buildup and reducing barriers to entry into the airline industry.
  2. Labor
    • Airlines are dependent on skilled employees, pilots and technical personnel. Network airlines (ones that operate hub-and-spoke model) are particularly vulnerable to disruptions at their hubs, which increases power of unions at these locations
    • Unions tend to be local monopolies. In airlines there are different unions for different types of staff, with each of them having the ability to disrupt operations. Union power and regulation have led to significant lack of downward flexibility in staffing levels and wages, especially for legacy airlines.
    • There are significant cost differences between new entrants, companies in bankruptcy protection, and unionized incumbents, where high wages continue to be paid relative to other industries, especially for employees with specialized skills like pilots.
    • Employees have traditionally one of the groups most successful in capturing the value created by the airline industry. They remain powerful where labor regulations and hub-and-spoke give them leverage. Because union power increases as companies mature, the nature of labor relations also erodes industry structure by encouraging entrants and bankruptcy to avoid union related costs, even if there is no productive advantage.
  3. Airports
    • Many airports are local monopolies with limited competition from nearby secondary airports. There is little entry by new airports, so the main check of the exploitation of market power is through regulation. The pricing power that the local monopoly gives to an airport depends significantly on the potential traffic flows to which it provides access.
    • Many airports in the US continue to be used by local governments to foster economic development through subsidizing airlines' operations. On average airports do not earn their cost of capital.
    • Airport switching costs are high, especially for network airlines that are focused on providing connections. It is easier for point-to-point airlines, especially low cost carriers (LCC) flying to larger metropolitan areas with a number of airports or regional airports not served by network airlines. 
    • Airports marginally better profitability compared to airlines indicates that their effective bargaining power has been limited. The main impact on airline industry structure has been through infrastructure capacity constraints and other operational practices that have limited effective capacity adjustments in serving particular connections
  4. Ground handling services / catering
    • They have limited bargaining power, largely because airlines have the option of providing the service in-house. 
Threat of Substitutes
The most powerful substitute to aircraft travel is the decision not to travel. 
  1. Time and inconvenience of security measures have reduced the overall attractiveness of scheduled airlines transport relative to substitutes.
  2. For short-haul connections, a key concern of airline passengers is punctuality. While airlines have some control, the key drivers for delays are the air control systems and airports.
  3. The slightly growing role of substitutes such as video conferencing for business travel has been driven by improvements in their performance and falling costs.
Threat of New Entrants
The threat of new entrants is high. Over 1,300 new airlines were established in the past 40 years, an average of over 30 each year. Entry has been highly cyclical. Remarkably, entry rates have shown no sign of slowing down despite low industry profitability.
  1. Economies of scale exist on the demand side, i.e. it is easier to generate demand with a strong brand, a wide distribution presence, and a large network of connections. There are also benefits from established operations in generating route density to allow larger aircraft (lower costs) and higher frequency (higher price). But since most of the entry is through existing airlines operating in adjacent geographies that do not face these barriers, these factors do not significantly deter entry.
  2. Supply-side economies of scale are limited as airlines grow beyond a level of around 50 aircraft. This creates some disadvantages for new airlines but not for existing ones looking to expand into new markets. Because capacity comes in lumps, airlines operating in adjacent geographies face the lowest entry barriers. They can serve a new destination through spare capacity on existing airplanes
  3. Access to distribution channels is easy for new entrants, much more so than in the past. GDSs and the internet now enable new airlines to list and make their flights available through a larger number of aggregator websites and travel agencies. This is a big change from the past where reservation systems and travel agents were controlled by incumbents.
  4. Legacy rights on slots give some advantages but there is secondary trading of slots at congested airports and thus no advantages until slot capacity is reached. If infrastructure does not grow in line with travel volumes, however, it can become an increasing bottleneck limiting entry at most frequented hubs.
  5. Substantial capital is needed to acquire a new aircraft. Prior to the financial crisis, however, external financing was widely available. The growing presence of leasing companies reduces capital requirements. However, it remains hard for new entrants to meet operational cash flow requirements during persistent downturns.

As you can see, the airline industry is squeezed by all the five forces causing it to have the worst economics for any industry. In fact, airlines capture the least value among all the players in the entire supply chain.


This concludes our discussion on the first question we raised at the beginning of this article: "Why does an industry have a high or low ROIC?". It's primarily a result of the five competitive forces that shape the industry structure. 

Just because the industry on the whole has been destroying value doesn't mean that there aren't individual operators that aren't achieving returns above the cost of capital. As a matter of fact, there are quite a few that have generated large economic value. This will be the purpose of the article in the next part in this series. We'll use the example of Southwest airlines to answer the remaining two questions raised at the beginning: "Why does a company have ROIC much higher than the rest of the industry?" and "What will be result of management's current actions on future ROIC?"


Southwest airlines, a low cost carrier, had a strong value creator record in 1980s and 1990s. However, during the 2000s, once the impact of the well timed fuel hedging is removed, Southwest seems to have destroyed capital. Thus, it is instructive to closely examine Southwest because it will answer both the remaining questions. To be continued.. 


References:
  • What is Strategy, Michael Porter, Harvard Business Review
  • The Five Competitive Forces that Shape Strategy, Michael Porter, Harvard Business Review
  • Understanding Porter, Joan Magretta, Harvard Business Review Press
  • Vision 2050, International Air Transport Association, Feb 2011

Wednesday, December 7, 2011

Economics of Two-Sided Markets and MasterCard

I pitched MasterCard on this blog (here) in Dec 2010 when it was trading at $225. My thesis worked out as I had laid out then, Federal Reserve came out with its final ruling on Durbin in July 2011 and it was more lenient than their original proposal in Dec 2010. Mr. Market responded to these news quite favorably and the stock is up 65% from the price at which I initiated my position. Today, I view MasterCard as being a bit overvalued, so I have no plans to add to this position. But since I have been talking about two-sided markets (here and here), I thought it would be a good idea to talk about how this applies to MasterCard.

When a consumer swipes her debit (or credit) card issued by a bank to pay for a $100 merchandise at Walmart, an entity known as the merchant acquirer charges Walmart an interchange fee in the range of 20-25c for the debit transaction. The setting of the interchange fee is a complicated matter and it's set by MasterCard. The merchant acquirer retains a small percent of the interchange fee and passes off a large portion to the issuer bank. MasterCard charges the bank a very small transaction fee for using the network, but net MasterCard is essentially letting the bank make the most from the interchange fee, hence the banks are on the subsidy side. MasterCard also makes a very small transaction fee from the acquirer. So, even though the merchant is not compensating MasterCard, I still consider it to be the money side of the network since it's the one paying for the subsidy MasterCard is providing to the banks.

I believe that understanding the pricing model is really important for one to understand MasterCard (or Visa's) competitive advantages to any possible threats from new entrants. When I talked to people about MasterCard, most people would just say - "plastic is a dying business, mobile payments will displace them". So, I want to address this issue. 

Plastic or wireless, businesses don't exist just purely on technology in any two sided market (remember the Adobe example). The economics matter for them to come into existence. So, let's conjure up some wireless payment company (Verizon, AT&T, Google, Apple or someone else) that is going to compete with Visa/MasterCard/Visa.

Can they get the banks to co-operate with them without Visa and MasterCard in the picture?
Why would Chase give up its huge revenue stream from the interchange fee (thanks to Visa/MasterCard) and  partner up with some cute technology company? They have no incentive to do so, unless these new networks provide a compelling reason - meaning interchange fee that is healthy enough to force them to upset their big money center, MasterCard/Visa. Where exactly is this network going to come up with this money to compensate the banks from? Either they are willing to lose billions for years or charge the merchants a fee even higher than the MasterCard/Visa's interchange fee. So, then why would merchants be enthusiastic of accepting this new technology if it costs of them more than traditional technology? I doubt banks will co-operate with the new networks if MasterCard/Visa are not part of the network.

Can the new networks compete without Visa/MasterCard and the banks?
Where are they going to make the money from? Executives at Apple are not sitting around conjuring up new ideas to go into without have a proper model of where the revenues are going to come from, are they? So either they charge the consumer on a per transaction basis or they charge the merchants. Let's explore the first idea - charge the consumers. This pricing model is like Adobe charging each reader of the PDF document a 5c viewing fee. Are you willing to pay such a fee? You can always find suckers for anything, but I doubt that the network can grow big enough to make any economic sense with this model. Then, the only place they can make money from is by charging the merchants. It can probably get traction with the merchants only if Apple  charges transaction fees that are lower than the current interchange fee (why would Walmart want to install new point-of-sale systems that accept Apple payments otherwise). But Apple has way fewer transactions when it starts out. So, it has to amortize the fixed costs of running a payment network over a much smaller revenue stream. 

Let's compare this to the cost structure of MasterCard/Visa. As per data put out by the Fed in Dec 2010, MasterCard/Visa make less than 2c per transaction from the big banks (which control 80% of payments) on debit transactions and my guess is that they make less than 10c on credit transactions from the big banks. Combine with the fact that they capture trillions of transactions (over 70% of all transactions) and hence they are able to cover the costs of running a business and make healthy margins. 

Apple (or any other mobile network that wants to do it on its own) basically must be willing to lose money for a long time before they can capture volumes that make the business economically viable. One may say that isn't running a payment network no incremental cost to running a voice network and the argument that Apple needs a large volume to amortize costs is incorrect? Payment networks are very different relative to voice networks. You can have missed calls on voice network, but not on a payment network. When was the last time you were stuck at a grocery line because the payment network was down. Most of the times it's because of a hold on the card, but not because the network is down. Payment networks need to be more secure than voice networks. I have had my credit card stolen online quite a few times, but every time it happened I didn't detect the theft, but a representative from MasterCard would call me to tell me that certain suspicious transactions were detected. As per data by the Fed, the costs of running fraud detection are not something you can just ignore. Would you be willing to use a payment network that didn't have this protection? 

Lastly, there is nothing from a business point of view that is stopping MasterCard/Visa to partner up with another technology that competes with the ones that goes out on its own. MasterCard/Visa can take a margin cut for a few years and subsidize the technology partner for acting as a replacement for plastic. Who would not want to get this low risk revenue stream that starts on day one? In fact, that is what MasterCard exactly did by partnering with Telefonica for mobile payments in Latin America. The margin squeeze is not even permanent, because MasterCard/Visa can probably make it up by raising the interchange fees over time. 

I know the word "moat" gets thrown around a lot, so its really important to understand the underlying reason for the "moat" before one declares a business to have a moat. Without this kind of understanding, it's hard to monitor if the moat of the business is growing or decaying. If I can't do this type of analysis, I don't want to call the business to have a moat or rely on it. 

I say both MasterCard/Visa have a moat and I encourage you to challenge my reasoning I laid out here. Feel free to leave a comment or email me at rgosalia at gmail dot com.

Monday, December 5, 2011

Economics of Two-Sided Markets and the Future of Newspapers - Part II

This is a continuation of a previous post I did a few days ago here where we talked about general economics of any two sided market.

Let's apply it to the news business (ideas mostly from Dr. Alstyne's talk at UC Berkeley Media Tech Summit):

Ability to Capture Cross-Side Effects: The emergence of new digital platforms brought about the weakening of the newspapers' ability to capture cross side effects. Newspapers' subsidy side, the subscribers, started to flock to free digital platforms (Yahoo, CNBC, blogs) to keep up with daily news. Newspapers' money side, the advertisers, started to move to digital platforms that were either free (Craigslist) or more efficient (Google).

Marginal Costs & Value Add: The newspaper executives were just too slow to re-innovate their business models. When news facts such as who won the election or what's happening in Iran cannot be owned, they were bound to be disinter-mediated as new means of distribution became available thanks to the internet and search engines. Instead of trying to protect "content" (which they don't own anyway), newspapers executives should have realized that the marginal cost of distributing digital news is very low relative to print, and should have driven readership to their own digital websites (happening but a bit too late). A portion of the (subscriber) print revenues could be replaced by a fee-model through value added services on top of the free news content. One could argue that if newspapers could have retained (can retain) their subsidy side, the money side, the advertisers, would continue to be attracted to the newspaper network (albeit at lower rates).

So what kind of value added services a digital newspaper have that could attract readership away from blogs and other low quality sites.
  1. Interactive Data: Data such as state-to-state employment rate cannot be owned, but having an interactive application (such as here) is a good example of a value add.
  2. Credentialing: Anyone can aggregate data, but the ability to validate data using sophisticated algorithms is another example of value add. FiveThirtyEight is a polling website (now a licensed feature of New York Times) that rates errors of polls and produces pretty accurate statistical models. 
  3. User Generated Content: Amazon and Slashdot essentially created a business around the concept of using user generated content to add value. Today you see it as comments on a story on a digital news article, but one could go further by helping a user clear the cutter in smart ways (again look at Amazon or Slashdot).
  4. Ability to search archives: The search engines algorithm are smart when you are trying to find content that is hyper linked. So if you were trying to find content that is a few years old (this is a just an argument for long-tail), then the newspapers could add value by letting you search their print archives. Now imagine if I could connect this with my stock portfolio and quickly get a news time line for the last 10 years for all articles that have shown up on WSJ print that in my opinion would be super useful. 
Price Sensitivity: Dr. Alstyne gives the example of "technical" journals he receives today that are free (subsidy side) and the contributor is the one who is charged to reach the vast audience. I am not sure how this exactly applies to the newspaper business, but price sensitivity is one area that could be further explored.

Having said all of the above, I think the newspaper business is a tough one to be in going forward. When you have a business that goes from being a monopoly to one that faces multiple competitive threats, it is not an easy transition. 

I encourage you to listen to (or read) John Temple's talk about the lessons he learnt as an editor and publisher at Rocky Mountain News, one of the top newspapers in Denver Colorado. He tells you what kind of internal forces were at play within the company as these industry headwinds were playing out. I find this kind of postmortem analysis very interesting as an investor because "All I want to know is where I am going to die, and I'll never go there" (Charlie Munger).

Thursday, December 1, 2011

Economics of Two-Sided Markets and the Future of Newspapers

Warren Buffett recently announced the purchase of his hometown newspaper company, Omaha World-Herald. I have no opinion on the purchase, but I am going to use this occasion to talk about the economics of  business' that are like that of newspapers and apply these economic principles to the evolving newspaper business. Before I begin, I want to acknowledge that my thoughts on this topic absolutely not original, but come from a Boston University professor, Marshall Van Alstyne, one of the top researchers in this area.


The newspapers are an example of a "two-sided markets". Two-sided markets are economic platforms that bring together two different user groups that provide each other with network benefits. Other examples include credit cards (cardholders and merchants), HMOs (patients and doctors), operating systems (end-users and developers), video game consoles (gamers and game developers), web search engines (searchers and advertisers), and social networks (web "socializers" and advertisers).


First we'll begin by going back to your Econ 101 class. Usually for a market, the demand curve is downward sloping and you lower the price until value on the next unit sold makes up for the losses on sales you would have made at a higher prices. As you would expect, it makes no sense to give away your product for free because that gives up all profits on every unit sold. What makes two-sided markets special, despite what  your Econ 101 class tells you, is that sometimes it can make sense to give away your product for free (or subsidize them) because it could stimulate demand in an adjacent market you own that more than makes up for the subsidy.

Let me give you an example that you may not have thought of. Consider Abode's Portable Document Format (PDF) format, a standard used for universal document exchange. The PDF network consists of two sets of users - writers, who create documents using Adobe's Acrobat Distiller software that costs them $499, and readers, who view these documents using Abode's Acrobat Reader software that they can download for free. Writers, who greatly value the huge reader audience, are more than willing to pay a fee for their software. Adobe's subsidy of giving away the PDF reader for free is more than compensated by the higher demand in its writer software. Now here is an instance where giving away something for free makes sense!

Unlike the traditional markets, economics in the two-sided markets are more complicated. Dr. Alstyne prescribes a few factors to think about in order to make the network work correctly.

User Sensitivity to Price: Had Adobe started out charging even a small fee to the price sensitive reader group, the network would not have grown as big as it is today. Subsidize the group that is price sensitive ("subsidy side") and charge the side ("money side") that increases its demand more strongly in response to the other side's growth

User Sensitivity to Quality: Counter-intuitively, rather than charging the side that strongly demands quality, you charge the side that supplies quality. Think about the video game market. Gamers demand quality and game developers must incur huge fixed costs to deliver this quality. In order to amortize this cost, they must be ensured that the game console platform has many users. Hence the need to subsidize the gamers with a below cost subsidy.  Console providers ensure that game developers meet high quality standards by imposing strict licensing terms and high royalty rates. This "tax" is not passed to the consumers: the game developers charge the highest rates the gamers will bear, independent of the royalty rate. However, the royalty rate helps weed out games of marginal quality. Once the "tax" is added, titles with poor sales prospects cannot generate enough margin to cover their fixed costs, so they never get made in the first place. 

Ability to Capture Cross-Side Effects: Your giveaway will be wasted if your network's subsidy side can transact with a competitive network's money size. This was Netscape's mistake. Netscape gave away its browsers to individuals in hopes of selling Web servers to companies operating web sites. But web site operators didn't have to buy Netscape's servers in order to send web pages to Netscape's big browser user base; they could easily buy a rival's web server instead.

Output Costs: Don't subsidize the product when each unit has appreciable costs. If a strong willingness to pay from the money side does not materialize, a giveaway with high variable costs can quickly rack up large losses. FreePC learned this lesson in 1999 when it provided Compaq computers and internet access at no cost to consumers who agreed to view internet ads that could not be minimized or hidden. Not surprisingly, few marketers were eager to target consumers who were so cost conscious. The decision is much simpler when the product subsidized is a digital good such as a Google web search, where the marginal cost of serving an additional user web search costs Google nothing.

Value Added: Even though Apple's Mac platform always commanded a premium from consumers, Microsoft was a winner that essentially monopolized the desktop operating system market. Desktop customers were attracted to Microsoft's Windows operating system because of the large number of applications that were only Windows compatible. This came about partly due to Apple's missteps and partly Microsoft's foresight. When Mac was launched, Apple's grave error was to extract rent from the software developers who developed applications for the Mac operating system by charging them $10,000 for Mac's software development kit (SDK). In contrast, Microsoft was smart enough to give away the Windows' SDK for free. By the time Microsoft went to anti-trust trial, Windows had six times as many applications as Mac!

Interfering same-side effects: Sometimes it makes sense to exclude certain users from your network. For example, many auto part manufacturers, concerned about downward pricing pressure, refused to participate in Covisint, a B2B exchange organized by auto manufacturers. Covisint stalled, as did many B2B exchanges that failed to attract enough sellers. In the face of high negative same-side network effects, network providers should consider granting exclusive rights to single user in each transaction category - and in exchange extract high concession for this rent. The network provider must also ensure that sellers do not abuse their monopoly positions; otherwise, buyers will not be attracted to their platform. 

Marquee Providers: The participation of "marquee users" can be especially important for attracting participants to the other side of the network. A platform provider can accelerate growth if it can secure the exclusive participation of marquee users in the form of commitment from them not join rival platforms. For many years, this kind of exclusive arrangement was at the core of Visa's marketing campaigns - remember ads that said "...and they don't take American Express"


Microsoft learned the hard lesson of not to upset your platform's marquee customers when Electronic Arts (EA) - the largest developer of video games and thus a major potential money side user of Microsoft Xbox platform - refused to create online, multiplayer versions of its games for Xbox Live service. EA objected to Microsoft's refusal to share subscription fees from Xbox Live, among other issues. After an 18 month stalemate, EA finally agreed to offer Xbox Live games. Even though terms of the agreement weren't disclosed, you can bet that they were generously tilted in favor of EA.

Now that we understand the economics of two-sided markets, I'll describe Dr. Alstyne's application of these principles to the evolving business of newspapers in part II of this article to follow in the next few days. Your comments are always welcome. Feel free to email me at rgosalia at gmail dot com.

References:
  • Information Business Models & The News: When Free Works and When it Doesn't, Marshall Van Alstyne, UC Berkeley Media Technology Summit 2009.
  • Strategies for Two-Sided Markets, Thomas Eisenmann, Geoffrey Parker, Marshall Van Alstyne, HBR


Sunday, November 20, 2011

Fundamentals of Value Creation

This section is heavily borrowed from the book "Valuation: Measuring and Managing the Value of Companies". In my opinion, this book has one of the clearest explanations on the drivers of value creation for a company. I say this after reading many books to try to understand this topic. At close to 800 pages, this is not an easy read, but if you are into this kind of thing, I promise it is worth the effort. 

Consider the following two hypothetical companies Value and Volume, whose projected revenues and earnings are identical. Both companies earn $100 million in year 1 and increase their revenues and earnings at 5 percent per year in all future periods, so their projected earnings are identical. Assume that shares outstanding for both companies are the same, so projected EPS for both are also identical. Here is a question - are the two companies' values also the same, or in technical terms, do they deserve the same P/E multiple? The investment community's fixation with EPS growth and P/E multiple would make you believe it to be true, but let me dispel this myth here.

Future growth does not come for free. Both companies have to reinvest a certain percentage of their earnings for the year to achieve future growth. Let's assume that company Value has to invest only 25% of its earnings back into the business but Volume has to reinvest back 50% of its earnings to achieve the same rate of growth as company Value. Thus, company Value creates higher cash flows (Earnings - Investments into the business for future growth) relative to company Volume. 


What remains for the shareholder are these streams of cash flows that she can expect to earn in future periods (through dividend payments for instance). Since "a bird in hand is worth two in the bush" you discount back (using the company's cost of capital) these future expected streams of cash flows to the current time and sum them up to get the intrinsic value for these two companies. Assuming that the cost of capital for both companies are the same, since company Value creates higher cash flows it is more valuable and deserves a higher P/E multiple than company Volume even though both have identical projected EPS' in future periods.

I can't tell you how often I listen to analysts saying "this company trades at 18x P/E and hence it is not cheap, look at this other company that trades at 10x P/E it is much cheaper". In an ideal world where all companies are required to put in same percentage of investment to achieve same rates of future growth, it makes sense to make these types of comparisons, but otherwise it is totally nonsensical.

Company Value achieves 5% of Growth each year by investing back 25% (also known as Investment Rate) of its earnings each year. The ratio of Growth / Investment Rate is known in the financial literature as ROIC (Return on Invested Capital). Thus, Value's ROIC is 20% and Volume's ROIC is 10%. 

Let's look at the valuation matrix for a company that earns $100 million in year one, has a long-term growth rate of 2% to 4%, ROIC of 10% to 16%, and a cost of capital of 10%.


A few observations - (i) the blue column shows that growth has no effect on value when ROIC is same as cost of capital, (ii) the two green cells show that a company with lower growth rate but higher ROIC can be just as valuable as one that has higher growth but lower ROIC, and (iii) the red cell shows that any growth below ROIC destroys value. 

With this new (and correct) way of looking at a business, you will find the constant touting of EPS growth for such and such a company on CNBC to be completely worthless information, especially since CNBC does not talk about ROIC or cost of capital for the business.

Let's talk about how I calculated the valuation matrix above. First, I need to introduce a few new terms. 
  • NOPAT (Net Operating Profit less Adjusted Taxes): represents profits generated from company's core operations after subtracting the income taxes related to the core operations
  • Invested Capital (IC): represents the cumulative amount the business has invested in its core operations - property, plant, and equipment, and working capital
  • Net Investment is the increase in investment capital from one year to the next
  • Free Cash Flow (FCF): is the cash flow generated by the core operations of the business after deducting investments in new capital. So, FCF = NOPAT - Net Investment
  • Return on Invested Capital (ROIC): is the return the company earns on each dollar invested in the business. So, ROIC = NOPAT / Invested Capital. ROIC can also be defined as the incremental return on new or incremental capital. However, for now we assume that both are the same. If not, then the later definition is known as RONIC (Return on New Invested Capital). 
  • Investment Rate (IR) is the portion of NOPAT invested back in the business. So, IR = Net Investment / NOPAT.
  • Weighted average cost of capital (WACC) is the return that investors expect to make from investing in the enterprise and therefore the appropriate discount rate for FCF.
  • Growth (g) is the rate at which NOPAT and cash flow grow each year. Investing the same proportion of NOPAT each year also means that the company's free cash flow grows at rate g.
Since company's free cash flow grows at a constant rate g, we can begin valuing the company by using the well-known formula for perpetual growth:

Enterprise Value = FCF / (WACC - g)  .........(1)

Next, lets define FCF in terms of NOPAT and IR.
FCF = NOPAT - Net Investment =>
FCF = NOPAT - NOPAT * IR   =>
FCF = NOPAT * (1-IR) ..............(2)

In the section on Value vs. Volume, we had seen that 
ROIC = g / IR =>
IR = g / ROIC ............(3)

so putting equation (3) and (2) in (1), you get
Enterprise Value = NOPAT (1 - g/ROIC) / (WACC - g)

If you put ROIC = WACC in the above formula, you get Value = NOPAT / WACC, a formula that is independent of g as we had seen in the blue column of the valuation matrix. 

If you divide by NOPAT on both sides, you get:
Enterprise Value / NOPAT = (1 - g/ROIC) / (WACC - g)

The Enterprise Value to NOPAT ratio (similar to the ratio used in Joel Greenblatt's ratio EV/EBIT but its pre-tax) is a more meaningful way of thinking about the appropriate multiple for a business instead of the usually quoted P/E multiple. As you can see the key drivers of this multiple are long-term growth rate for the business, ROIC, and the cost of capital. 

Lets apply this to one of the businesses I own today - MasterCard. I expect MasterCard to grow at 15% to 20% for the next 5 years and do it at a very high ROIC of 40% to 50%. However, this cannot last forever. Growth rates slow down as markets get saturated and ROIC goes down as opportunities to invest capital go down. It seems unlikely that new competition can come in and start competing with MasterCard in the foreseeable future for a long time (for reasons I will not go into here, but you can look at my MasterCard write-up from December 2010). Thus, once the fast growth period ends, I expect MasterCard to be able to continue growing at least 1% to 2% above inflation of 2% (due to pricing power in absence of competition) and continue to do it at ROIC of 15% to 20%. I use 10% as the WACC for MasterCard. Plug this into the formula, you get a multiple of 11x to 13x of 2016E NOPAT. Since NOPAT can grow at 15% to 20% in the 5 years from 2012-2016, 2016E NOPAT will be at 2x to 2.5x of 2011 NOPAT. Hence, the fair value of MasterCard is between 22x to 30x of 2011 NOPAT + sum of free cash flows generated for the years 2011 through 2016 discounted to present (which we'll ignore for simplicity sake). When I purchased MasterCard in Dec 2010, it was trading at 14.5x of 2010 NOPAT. It's up 60% from my purchase price and today it is trading at 19x 2011 NOPAT. 

Let me give you another example. For the period from 1968 to 2007, net income at the pharmacy chain, Walgreens, grew at 14% annually and it was among the fastest growing companies in the United States. During this period, the average annual shareholder return (including dividends) was 16%. Now, contrast this with performance at the chewing gum maker Wm. Wrigley Jr. Company during the same period. Wrigley's net income during the same period grew much slower at about 10% a year, but the average annual shareholder return of 17% a year was higher than at Walgreens. The reason Wrigley could create more value than Walgreens despite 40% slower growth was that it earned a 28% ROIC, while the ROIC for Walgreens was 14% (which is quite good for a retailer).

Next time you hear the words "this company is trading at only 10x P/E, it must be cheap. Or this company that is at 18x P/E must be expensive", I urge you to think about this article. In all likelihood the conclusion may be the correct one, but think about the business' ROIC and what about its structure causes it to have a high (or a low) ROIC before drawing that conclusion.

Thursday, November 17, 2011

Tableau Software: Amazing Tool for Data Analysis and Viewing

I downloaded the free trial of a new software called Tableau yesterday. It is one slick tool - you use your excel sheet as the data source and connect Tableau to it. Once done, you can quickly slice, dice and view your data in more ways that you imagine. I was pretty impressed. It costs a thousand bucks, so I am not sure if I'll make the jump yet, but I am a sucker for these kinds of things. Here is what I put together in under 10 minutes - a tool that shows My U.S. Portfolio performance relative to Vanguard's S&P500 index fund. You can use the slider to move the reference start date and then click on the points on the two line charts to get cumulative performance from the reference date.


Monday, November 14, 2011

American Business Bank: Growth at a Reasonable Price

I initiated a new position in a tiny L.A. based bank, American Business Bank (OTC:AMBZ), recently at an average price of $21.60. It is now a 4% position in the portfolio. AMBZ trades over-the-counter and has no SEC filings, but no reason to worry since its financials can be verified with call reports that AMBZ is required to file with FDIC.

American Business Bank operates in the niche of banking middle market companies. The narrow focus has served AMBZ really well - assets have grown from less than 100M when the bank opened its doors in 1998 to over a billion dollars today. Net income has grown from less than a million to over ten million today. If you looked at its financials, you would not know that the US banking sector just experienced the worst crisis since the Great Depression. It has had virtually no non-accruals, no OREO, or net charge offs. Despite this, the balance sheet today has close to 2% of net loans in reserves for future loan losses. Furthermore, its cost of funding is among the lowest, if not the lowest in the nation at 35 bps. It has achieved these enviable results by consistently doing a ROAE of 12% to 14%. 

Despite this, AMBZ trades at a very small premium to tangible book value of $18.80 and at 9x TTM P/E of $2.33. I believe that a position in AMBZ today presents the opportunity to make a total return of 50% to 200% as it grows its asset base to $1.5 to $2 billion by 2016 with no downside in any scenario that I can imagine (market volatility is not considered as downside - we are talking about chances of permanent loss).

Here is a link to the detailed write-up. 

Tuesday, October 18, 2011

Nicholas Financial: Quality on Sale

I recently added to my previously held position, Nicholas Financial (NASDAQ:NICK), at $9.74. Nicholas is in the business of making sub-prime auto loans.

Contrary to the business description, it is one of the highest quality financial that I have come across - it has continued to stay profitable over the past decade consistently doing Returns on Average Equity (ROAE) of 10% to 15% (with the exception of 2008 when ROAE dropped to 6%), despite this period being one of the worst for financials since the depression. It is one of the few financials that continues to grow in this dismal environment of poor loan demand and does not face as big a risk of net interest margin compression as the conventional banks.

At current valuations, the upside is of 70% to 150% over the next 5 years, or an IRR of 11% to 20%. Add to this a dividend yield of 4%, you get a very compelling IRR of 15% to 24%, and a very limited chance of permanent loss of capital, thanks to its conservatively reported book value of $10 per share.

For a full write up, I recommend you read my submission for Gurufocus' October Value Contest here

Sunday, August 21, 2011

2011 Portfolio Update

This is first post in four months since my write-up on CVS Caremark. Yes, I am still alive and kicking. I have been very busy in the past few months learning about the banking and insurance business, researching for new ideas, and writing new ideas at www.valueinvestorsclub.com (VIC). Unfortunately, writing on the blog fell to the bottom of my list of things to do.

For those who are unfamiliar with VIC, it is an exclusive forum of only 250 value investors who share long and short ideas on the forum.  The club was started by the renowned author and hedge fund manager Joel Greenblatt. To be selected to the club, one writes up a “deeply researched” long or short position to be judged by a panel of VIC judges. I got selected to the club based on my write-up on MasterCard. I feel extremely fortunate to be part of the club – in less than 6 months I feel like I have learnt more than I ever have in my investing career by interacting with one of the smartest groups of value investors out there. One of the restrictions of VIC is that ideas posted there cannot be shared publicly. Unfortunately it means that, going forward, ideas that I post there or I learn of there will not show up in much detail on this blog.

Uncertainty and volatility has returned to markets. Correlation between asset classes has increased dramatically and almost all investing decisions today seemed to be made on increasingly short time horizons. The prevalence of algorithmic trading has reduced the already short-termed nature of a large number of market participants to holding periods of minutes, if not seconds! The only thing I know I will be doing is what I know to do – buy good businesses that are low in leverage, have low risk of obsolescence, and are offered by Mr. Market at an attractive price. Undoubtedly, this will be accompanied with a mark down in market prices of businesses we own today and will own through this environment. I will not let this bother me much since I continue to be confident that Ben Graham was right when he said “Mr. Market is a voting machine in the short-run, and a weighing scale in the long-run.”

Next, I want to talk about the portfolio’s performance. Even though portfolio’s YTD performance has beaten S&P500, it has been dissatisfactory to say the least – portfolio -6.8% YTD compared to S&P500 (with dividends reinvested) -10.39% YTD. To congratulate oneself based on comparisons with other indices is idiotic, since we do not eat from the plate of relative performance. Looking at a more longer horizon, the portfolio held up much better, +12.15% cumulative growth since 1/1/2010 relative to –0.52 cumulative growth in S&P500 (with dividends reinvested) since 1/1/2010. My longer term goal is to have the portfolio CAGR at inflation plus 10%.

CumulativeGrowth-8192011

Let me update you on the changes in the portfolio from the last time I reported. I sold out of four positions – three of them had reached their “intrinsic value” and the forth one, FUR,  I was wrong on and sold at a reasonable profit.

PositionsSold-8192011

FUR is structured as a REIT – meaning it has to pay out a large portion of the FFO to the owners – causing the REIT to keep coming back to the capital market every time it wants to grow. FUR had become a 25% position in my portfolio, and the only way I could stay undiluted was to participate in the capital raise. I was super uncomfortable with a position larger than what I already had. The reason for selling out had more to do with the function of a REIT in my portfolio rather than Mr. Ashner’s skills, who is one of the smartest real estate investors I have come across. If the price becomes right, I may start a very small position again in the future.

Now, let me turn your attention to the current positions in the portfolio.

CurrentPositions8192011

Note: Foreign holdings such as Accor and Edenred have been converted to USD on a mark to market basis. The Gains % column indicates gains in market value of the security including dividends yielded since the time of purchase of the security.

I will make a comment on my thesis on each of the holdings starting with a long comment on the ones that had the largest negative impact on the portfolio and a short one on the ones that have had the largest positive impact. I believe that we learn more from our “failures” than our “successes.” (All of the above is just mark to market – so failures and successes have limited meaning).

Kirkland’s (KIRK) – I initiated my position in KIRK, a specialty retailer, in Nov 2010 when it got really cheap (2x EV/EBITDA) due a couple of factors – gross margin compression due to higher than expected discounting and promotional activity, and operating margin compression due to deleverage caused by falling same-store-sales. The closest comp, Pier 1 (PIR) was trading at 5x EV/EBITDA. My wife and I have been shopping at KIRK since the time we bought our home a few years ago, so I was familiar with their concept. I viewed their problems more short term in nature and viewed this as a 2x given that KIRK had a long runway in front of it as it expanded its store count. KIRK has about 300 stores whereas Pier 1 has about 1200 stores, so it wasn’t unreasonable to assume that KIRK could get to 400-500 stores by 2015, as long as the economy remained somewhat stable. KIRK moved up by 30% in less than a few months, but I didn’t sell out, because I viewed it as a compounder over the next 5 years. Mistake #1 – valuation is not an exact science, hence the need to invest using a margin of safety. I should have taken 30% gains and got out. KIRK was back to where I started my position by the time it reported next quarterly results. Old issues (which I viewed as temporary) were still a concern but no new issues came up on the call other than a slow down in growth of new stores due to difficulty in finding new locations. KIRK management was now projecting growth of 20 net new stores in 2011 rather than 40. 20 new stores still got you 100 new stores in 5 years. My thesis remained intact, so I doubled up on my position. Mistake #2 – I should have nibbled at it, rather than doubling up. A small store like KIRK has massive operating leverage at work, so a lot of little issues can cause major swings in their margins (even though they may be temporary) causing volatility in the stock price as the street is focused on those little things. The volatility meant that I could have added to my position as it went down, and if it didn’t go down I still had a reasonable sized position to get a good enough upside. There was no reason to double up on one shot. A few weeks later, KIRK was down 25% primarily due to macro concerns. Today, KIRK is insanely cheap – EV of 85M, fortress balance sheet with no debt, and a EBITDA ranging from 30-60M in 2008-2010. KIRK reported its quarterly results on Aug 19, 2011 and nothing much has changed business wise. They are working through their issues – by changing merchandise mix to help lower the promotional activity and stabilize same-store-sales. They also announced that they will be using 40M of excess cash on balance sheet for buybacks in the next 18 months. When the stock is so cheap and the issues are temporary, use of excess cash to do buybacks is highly accretive to the shareholder. 40M of cash at today’s price will buyback 25% of their outstanding stock! Even if net income does not grow from 2011E of 20M, EPS grows from by 33% from $1 to $1.33. If they fix their issues in the next 18 months, Mr. Market will come back and award KIRK with the multiple it deserves of 10x – $13. In addition they will have generated another 30M or $2 of cash by then. So, conservatively we should see it go back to $13-$15 in 18 months – an IRR of 16% from my cost basis, or if you are starting a new position an IRR of 40% from today.

POSCO (PKX) is a one of the lowest cost producers of steel in the world based in Korea. It is the third largest in terms of production, and among the most profitable, if not the most. In an industry that is highly cyclical, it has achieved the rarity – consistently earned returns above the cost of capital for over a decade. In 2010, it reported one of the lowest margins in the last decade due to weakness in steel prices and increase in raw material costs. POSCO is taking the right steps to lower its raw material costs, so I am expecting that margins will eventually revert to mean. In my estimate, POSCO (ADR) is worth about $150 – 40% higher than my cost basis and 70% higher than today. Not baked into this valuation is a free option on India growth. POSCO has in-plans the largest foreign direct investment of 12B USD in India to create a FINEX plant with 12M capacity in the state of Orissa. FINEX is POSCO’s proprietary technology of steel making that can operate at 15% lower operating costs and 20% lower capex than traditional blast furnace.

With the new macro concerns surfacing, if we do double dip into a global recession, steel demand will continue to stay weak putting pressure on margins. Margin reversion-to-mean will take longer than I originally thought (five years instead of three) lowering my IRR in POSCO from 11% to 7%. My mistake on this position was one of incorrect sizing – even before the dip of 17% - at my cost basis, I was expecting a low double digit IRR which clearly did not justify a 8% position in the portfolio. I wonder now what I was thinking when I picked such a large position size! If POSCO goes back to my cost basis, I will reduce my position size. I will add to this position only if it goes below $50 (to bring my cost basis to $75 and an expected IRR of 15%).

Look for the second part of this post for comments on the next 4-5 positions, hopefully by the next weekend.

Friday, April 22, 2011

CVS Caremark: Toll Booth on Prescription Drug Spending Highway

CVS Caremark (NYSE:CVS) is the newest position in the portfolio. The position was initiated at an average cost of $33.50 and now occupies 8% of the portfolio. It represents the largest purchase since the Leucadia purchase in July 2010 resulting from a very deep analysis of its business and industry dynamics. My wife thought I was getting ready to take some exam during my research, because I spent non-stop six days a week staying up till 4:00 am for about a month.

CVS Caremark operates the largest retail drug store and the second largest PBM (prescription benefits manager) in the nation. It is the largest purchaser of prescription drugs in the world making it the Wal-Mart of the prescription drug supply industry.

To understand briefly on why this position was initiated, refer to the Summary section of my report at www.gurufocus.com (submitted for their monthly Value Contest). 

The full-report is also published at the link above, but to go through the report in its entirety, you will need patience along with a cup of coffee. The 40 page long report may seem over-the-board to some people, but when you purchase a stock, somebody else is on the other side of the trade, and only one of you can be right. It better be you if you are putting 8% of your net worth into the purchase.

Thursday, March 10, 2011

Wendy's/Arby's: Business Analysis & Valuation

Recently, I initiated a position in Wendy's/Arby's (NYSE:WEN) at an average cost of $4.79. WEN is led by the activist investor Nelson Peltz. He is well known for his ability to turnaround under-performing businesses by forcing changes that help improve operations. At the price WEN was purchased, the risk/reward profile is very attractive, especially in a frothy market like today where value has become very difficult to find. The downside is close to 0% and the upside is in the range of 35-50%. 

For a full report on WEN, refer to my article at www.gurufocus.com. For those who are not familiar with this website, it is well known among the value investing circle as a valuable resource for tracking activity of top value managers. This article was written as my contribution for a monthly contest that they run for best value ideas.

Saturday, January 1, 2011

Annual Report: Looking Back at 2010

2010Performance

This article is an update on 2010 performance of my investment portfolio. If you curious about why I update this on a public forum, you can read my reasoning in the Sept 2010 semi-annual report.

The equity portion of the portfolio was up by 22.58% relative to beginning of 2010. Accounting for cash & cash equivalents, portfolio was up by 20.37%. These numbers are net of all broker commissions and expenses. In comparison, in the same time-frame, S&P500 was up by 12.78% , Gold was up by 31.41%, and BSE Sensex was up by 17.43% (excludes costs of investing in the asset class). Really the closest comparison is S&P500, but I picked others simply because the masses are excited about these classes today. I believe that the portfolio’s performance was achieved with lower overall risk compared to any of these other asset classes, since the positions in the portfolio were purchased at an average discount of 30-60% of its intrinsic value and the portfolio maintained 10-20% cash through the entire year. I am not sure if one could say the same about the other asset classes. At the end of the year, cash dropped to 10% as a portion of cash was put to work in two new ideas in Nov & Dec.

Kirklands was purchased at an average cost of $12.10 at a surprisingly low valuation of Enterprise Value to EBITDA (EV/EBITDA) ratio of 2x. Kirklands fell from a high of $25 to $10 due to undue concerns about rising shipping costs and fall in margins. Its closest competitor Pier 1 Imports traded at EV/EBITDA of 6x at the time of purchase. Kirklands has one of highest inventory turnover in the industry and is one of the lowest cost provider.

MasterCard was purchased at $225. You can read the extensive analysis of MasterCard that was conducted before putting the cash to work in this position. This is typical of the process that I follow before investing in a specific idea. 

2010Top10

Frankly, I have mixed feelings despite the ‘market-beating’ performance of the portfolio. I am happy that it did so well, but I am surprised it happened so soon. When these positions were established in the earlier part of 2010, I had prepared myself to be patient for 1-3 years for 15-20% performance. Now with the price for many of these positions hovering around fair value (Leucadia, Ensco, Accor, Edenred), the margin of safety of holding them is much lower. This situation creates a bit of a challenge in terms of portfolio management. Since its been less than a year, selling them now would force the portfolio to part away with 30% of the gains to Uncle Sam. Giving away 30% of the gains would reduce the net gain of the portfolio from 20% to 15%. There are two ways to address this issue – either wait for the one year anniversary to sell out the fairly valued positions or add new assets to the portfolio to reduce the impact of these fairly valued positions to the portfolio. I am not sure which of these options should be chosen yet, but both aren’t too appealing. Holding fairly valued positions is not fun, since the margin of safety is smaller (higher risk lower reward). Adding new assets is not easy, because saving takes time. I really would have preferred a more slower recognition of value over a time frame of one year or more.

Lastly, I don’t think its going to easy to repeat the 20% performance again in 2011. In fact, I do not like to set goals for performance returns. Such goals force one to take unjustified risks. The only goal I have is to do better than inflation by about 10% on a long-term basis of 5-10 years. With the market run up, value has become really hard to find. I spend a lot of time looking at different ideas, but nothing so far meets the strict criteria of value. Since my primary goal is not beating the market, but to do well on an absolute basis (10% + inflation), I have no compelling reason to act. I would rather sit around waiting for a ‘fat pitch’. A ‘fat pitch’ is a term from baseball where the ball is pitched perfectly in the middle of the strike zone that a batter is completely confident in swinging at. Fortunately in the game of investing, any ball that is not a ‘fat pitch’ can be easily passed without being called out a strike. I do not mind twiddling my thumb until then. (I am not really twiddling my thumbs, but turning a lot of pages of 10Ks).

I will write again the status of the portfolio at the end of the half year on Jul 1 2011. Happy New Year !